Random Variables

EC 380 - Ricardian Model

Jose Rojas-Fallas

2025

Why Trade?

Quick Recap

Why does trade occur? This is our main question.

There are two strands within the field of international trade:

I. Neoclassical Models of Trade (‘Old Theories’):

  • Ricardian Model \(\Rightarrow\) Technology differences spur trade
  • Hecksher-Ohlin Model \(\Rightarrow\) Resource differences spur trade

II. ‘New’ Trade Theory:

  • Krugman Model \(\Rightarrow\) Demand/Want of variety spurs trade
  • Melits Model \(\Rightarrow\) Heterogenous firms drive trade

US Imports Snapshot

In 2022, the US imported $316M in Toothbrushes.
Roughly 56% from China alone. Next noticeable sources are Germany, Switzerland, and India.


The US represents the largest economy in the world. But it still resorts to import of goods at a level that far exceeds what it exports.


As an example, while 99% of shipping containers that enter the Los Angeles port are fully loaded with goods, 70% of containers leaving the port are empty!

Imports

Exports

Reasons for Trade

With all the manufacturing capacity of the US, why not make toothbrushes at home and consume them domestically?

  • Technology differences in each country?
  • Total resources available differ by country?
  • Production cost differences?
  • Proximity to countries with more productive labor forces?

For now, let’s consider the opportunity cost of doing so. The Ricardian Perspective says that the US devotes domestic labor that would otherwise be used to produce these toothbrushes to comparatively more productive tasks.

Comparative Advantage

During the 16th and 17th century, the study of economics was in its infancy. Misguided beliefs in public policy were widely held across nations.

Mercantalism: A stockpile of gold and silver was considered an appropriate barometer for the state of the domestic economy

Imports \(\Rightarrow\) Less gold

Exports \(\Rightarrow\) More gold

Tariffs are set high to prevent trade deficits’

Ricardo would demonstrate that under balanced free trade (no tariffs), trade then benefits every country

Ricardo’s Logic

If every country exports the goods in which they have the comparative advantage in, then every country benefits from trade

Let’s view at an example

  • Two countries: Portugal and England
  • Two goods: Wine and Cloth
  • Portugal has the absolute advantage in production of both goods
  • England is particularly bad at making wine, which makes it relatively good at producing cloth

England has the comparative advantage in cloth. Portugal has the comparative advantage in wine.

Ricardo says that both are better off trading than under autarky

Autarky

Autarky

Definition: The complete absence of foreign trade; total self-sufficiency of a national economy

To understand how trade affects national welfare, we have to understand how they do on their own

We can do this by looking at the Production Possibilities Curve (PPC)

  • These show the trade-offs when a country chooses their production combination of two goods
  • It is closely related to the opportunity cost of the good on the horizontal axis

Production Possibilities Curves (PPC)

For the moment, we will be dealing with PPCs that look like straight lines because we assume that the trade-off between two goods does not change

  • This follows from an assumption we make on labor: Labor is homogeneous and no group of workers is more skilled than another group

How are they related to opportunity costs?

  • Opportunity costs are the best forgone alternative: In order to produce 1 unit of good X, the country has to give up some amount of good Y.

    • Because this is a “rate of change”, we say that the slope of the PPC is the Opportunity Cost of good X

Production Possibilities Curves (PPC)

Country’s PPC Between X & Y

Production Possibilities Curves (PPC)

Country’s Bundle Choices Between X & Y

  • Point A: Producing at an inefficient and wasteful level
  • Point B: Efficient point of production where maximum level of output is obtained
  • Point C: Infeasible. The country does not have the resources to produce at this level

How Does a Country Optimally Choose?

Choice depends on the country’s demand for the two goods

We call these Indifference Curves

  • Each curve shows the consumption bundles of goods that the economy can consume and be equally satisfied

  • The consumers are indifferent in its own preference across the bundles on a particular indifference curve

Indifference Curves

Back to the Ricardo Model

Starting with the Ricardo Model, we look at it’s primary components:

  • Single Factor of Production (Labor)
  • Two-Country Model (Home and Foreign)
  • Technology differences across countries

We will use our own example

  • Factor of production: Labor (L)
  • Two Countries: Home and Foreign
  • Two Goods: Coffee and Tea
  • Suppose that in this case, the Home Country exports coffee and imports tea
  • What would this imply about which good each country has comparative advantage in?

Ricardo Model Assumptions

Creating PPFs

Let each country have a labor force size of 10 and productions be:

We find the PPF intercepts by seeing how much a country will produce if their entire work force only produces one good

Home would produce:

\[\begin{align*} &\text{Coffee:} \; L * \text{units} = 10 * 9 = 90 \\ &\text{Tea:} \; L * \text{units} = 10 * 7 = 70 \end{align*}\]

Home PPF

Slope of PPF is Opportunity Cost of Good X

Which is how much units of tea do I give up to make one more unit of coffee

\[ \text{Slope of PPF} = \dfrac{\Delta \text{Tea Ouptut}}{\Delta \text{Coffee Output}} = \dfrac{-7}{9} = \text{(-)Opportunity Cost of Coffee} \]

Introducing some Key Variables - Marginal Product of Labor

Marginal Product of Labor (MPL): Represents the additional units of a good produced, given a one unit increase in the number of workers assigned to a particular task

The MPL for the Home Country for each good is written as \(\text{MPL}_{c}^{H}\) and \(\text{MPL}_{t}^{H}\), for coffee and tea respectively.

We can assign numbers to each such that:

\[ \text{MPL}_{c}^{H} = 9 \;\;\;\; \& \;\;\;\; \text{MPL}_{t}^{H} = 7 \]

Let’s also say that the country has a full labor force \(\bar{L} = 10\)

We will add the Foreign Country later

Home PPF

We can plot the Home PPF by finding the intercepts for each good. We can do this by multiplying the marginal product of labor by the workforce size

\[ \text{MPL}_{\text{good}}^{\text{country}} * \bar{L} \]

The Home Country produces

\[\begin{align*} Q_{\text{coffee}}^{H} &= 9 * 10 = 90 \\ \\ Q_{\text{tea}}^{H} &= 7 * 10 = 70 \end{align*}\]

Home PPF

Assume: PPF is a straight line due to the constant MPLs

Slope of PPF: Equal to the marginal rate of substitution between goods (Coffee & Tea)

\[ \text{Slope of PPF}^{H} = -\dfrac{\text{MPL}_{t}}{\text{MPL}_{c}} = -\dfrac{7}{9} \]

This is also the Opportunity Cost of coffee. So we can say that if we want one more unit of coffee we must trade off tea at a rate of \(\dfrac{7}{9}\)

Equivalently, the opportunity cost of tea would be \(\dfrac{9}{7}\) units of coffee

Home Prices

We can determine prices in the country from this information as well. We assume to be under Perfect Competition which means that all goods are sold at cost.

Prices

These are in terms relative to both goods and measured in units:

\[ P_{c}^{H} = \dfrac{\text{MPL}_{t}}{\text{MPL}_{c}} = \dfrac{7}{9} \;\;\;\;\; \& \;\;\;\;\; P_{t}^{H} = \dfrac{\text{MPL}_{c}}{\text{MPL}_{t}} = \dfrac{9}{7} \]

Home Wages

We use the Perfect Competition assumptions to also determine wages

Wages

Workers are paid the equivalent of their MPL times the price of that additional unit they produce:

\[\begin{align*} \text{wages}_{\text{coffee}} &= \text{P}_{\text{coffee}} * \text{MPL}_{\text{coffee}} \\ \\ \text{wages}_{\text{tea}} &= \text{P}_{\text{tea}} * \text{MPL}_{\text{tea}} \end{align*}\]

Home Wages Across Industries

Additionally, because we assume that labor moves freely between industries, we can assume that wages are equalized across industries

\[ \text{wages}_{\text{coffee}} = \text{P}_{\text{coffee}} * \text{MPL}_{\text{coffee}} = \text{P}_{\text{tea}} * \text{MPL}_{\text{tea}} = \text{wages}_{\text{tea}} \]


We can rearrange this such that the price ratio is equal to the MPL ratio

\[ \dfrac{\text{P}_{\text{coffee}}}{\text{P}_{\text{tea}}} = \dfrac{\text{MPL}_{\text{tea}}}{\text{MPL}_{\text{coffee}}} \]

Relative price of coffee is equal to the Opportunity Cost of coffee at the autarky/no-trade equilibrium

Foreign PPF, Prices, and Wages

We can find the Foreign Country results as well

Find them for yourself. Let:

\[ \text{MPL}_{c}^{F} = 10 \;\;\;\;\; \& \;\;\;\;\; \text{MPL}_{t}^{F} = 12 \;\;\;\;\; \& \;\;\;\;\; \bar{L} = 10 \]

Tasks

  • Graph the Foreign Country PPF
  • Slope of \(\text{PPF}\)
  • Opportunity Cost of coffee and tea
  • Prices for both goods

Foreign Country

Foreign PPF

Opportunity Costs

  • Coffee: \(\dfrac{12}{10}\) \(\;\;\) & \(\;\;\) Tea: \(\dfrac{10}{12}\)

Prices

  • Coffee: \(\dfrac{12}{10}\) \(\;\;\) & \(\;\;\) Tea: \(\dfrac{10}{12}\)

Comparing Countries

Who Has the Advantage?

We can compare both countries and determine who has an advantage in production

We work with two types of advantages:

  • Absolute Advantage: If the country produces more per labor input
  • Comparative Advantage: If the country’s Opportunity Cost of producing a good is lower than the other country

Who Has the Advantage?

Now we have two countries, we can begin to compare their Marginal Productivities of Labor

  • A nation has the Absolute Advantage in a good if they produce more per labor input

  • A nation has the Comparative Advantage if the Opportunity Cost of producing a good is lower than that of the other country

Absolute Advantage

Foreign in both goods

Comparative Advantage

Home in Coffee | Foreign in Tea

Choosing Production Based on Preferences

Under Autarky, every country has to produce as much as they want to consume

We saw that the production bundle is determined by the country indifference curve

  • We won’t go into how we determine preferences, but we will figure out how to get exact bundles based on a pre-determined mix of goods

  • We are looking for a point where 2 curves (lines) touch

    • Which is equivalent to finding out at which coordinates they are equal to each other

    • We will have 2 equations (PPF & Preferences) and 2 unknowns (Good X and Good Y)

Choosing Production - Example

Let there be two countries, one belongs to the Vampires and the other to the Wolves with the following productivities and a labor force size of \(\bar{L} = 20\)

We will focus on the Vampires for this example:

  • They have prefer to consume 3 Sparkling Selfies for every 2 Shirtless Selfies

  • We will find how many Sparkling and Shirtless selfies the Vampires need to produce in order to satisfy demand

Vampires Production Bundle


\[ \bar{L} = 20 \]

We will:

  • Find the PPF intercepts
  • Find the proportion in which they prefer to consume the goods
  • Determine the PPF line
  • Set preferences proportion equal to PPF line and solve

Find PPF Intercepts

Looking only at the Vampires with \(\bar{L} = 20\)

We need to find the maximum they can produce for each good:

Sparkling

\[\begin{align*} \text{Max Sparkling} &= \text{MPL}_{spark} * \bar{L} \\ \text{Max Sparkling} &= 12 * 20 \\ \text{Max Sparkling} &= 240 \end{align*}\]

Shirtless

\[\begin{align*} \text{Max Shirtless} &= \text{MPL}_{shirt} * \bar{L} \\ \text{Max Shirtless} &= 4 * 20 \\ \text{Max Shirtless} &= 80 \end{align*}\]

Preference in Consuming Goods

We were told that Vampires prefer to consume 3 Sparkling selfies for every 2 Shirtless selfies

Let’s see how this translates to our indifference curve concept

\[\begin{align*} \dfrac{\text{Sparkling}}{\text{Shirtless}} = \dfrac{3}{2} \\ \end{align*}\]

\[\begin{align*} \dfrac{\text{Sparkling}}{\text{Shirtless}} &= \dfrac{3}{2} \\ 2 * \text{Sparkling} &= 3 * \text{Shirtless} \\ \dfrac{2}{3} * \text{Sparkling} &= \text{Shirtless} \end{align*}\]

Determining the PPF Line



The PPF Line

\[\begin{align*} \text{Y} &= b \pm mx \\ \text{Y} &= 80 - \dfrac{80}{240} * x \\ \text{Y} &= 80 - \dfrac{1}{3} * x \end{align*}\]

Putting It Altogether

Because we are finding where Production equals Demand, we are finding where these two equations equal each other

\[ \text{Shirtless} = \dfrac{2}{3} * \text{Sparkling} \;\;\;\;\; \& \;\;\;\;\; \text{Shirtless} = 80 - \dfrac{1}{3} * \text{Sparkling} \]

\[\begin{align*} \dfrac{2}{3} * \text{Sparkling} &= 80 - \dfrac{1}{3} * \text{Sparkling} \\ \left(\dfrac{2}{3} + \dfrac{1}{3} \right) * \text{Sparkling} &= 80 \\ (1) * \text{Sparkling} &= 80 \\ \text{Sparkling} &= 80 \end{align*}\]

Putting It Altogether

We know that Vampires will make 80 Sparkling selfies

Now we need to find how many Shirtless selfies they make:

There are two ways to find this out:

\[ \text{Shirtless} = \dfrac{2}{3} * \text{Sparkling} \;\;\;\;\; \text{or} \;\;\;\;\; \text{Shirtless} = 80 - \dfrac{1}{3} * \text{Sparkling} \]

\[\begin{align*} \text{Shirtless} &= \dfrac{2}{3} * 80 \\ \text{Shirtless} &\approx 53.3 \end{align*}\]

\[\begin{align*} \text{Shirtless} &= 80 - \dfrac{1}{3} * 80 \\ \text{Shirtless} &= 80 - 26.67 \\ \text{Shirtless} &\approx 53.3 \end{align*}\]

Results!

By knowing in which proportion consumers prefer their goods, we can find how much the country will produce under autarky

We could also figure out what happens to production if there is some form of shock to the economy, for example:

  • Preferences change
  • Labor increases/decreases
  • Productivities change

Trade

Why Would Foreign Trade?

Foreign is outright better at producing Coffee & Tea than Home. How could they benefit from trading with a less productive country?


  • If Foreign doesn’t trade, they are bound by their own production possibilities. With trade, they can exceed their own production capacities, even when they hold an Absolute Advantage

  • The same logic can be applied to Home. They will be able to exceed domestic production capacity by trading.

  • To trade, both nations must be better off from doing so. This will mean that the relative price of the good should fall somewhere in between both markets

  • Prices for each country are just the opportunity costs of the good

Gains from Trade - Home

The relative price of the good in the world market should fall somewhere in between both countries prices


\[\begin{align*} P_{c}^{H} &< P_{c}^{W} < P_{c}^{F} \\ \\ \dfrac{7}{9} &< P_{c}^{W} < \dfrac{12}{10} \end{align*}\]

Let the World Price be \[ P_{c}^{W} = 1 \Rightarrow \text{Slope} = -1 \]

Gains from Trade - Foreign

The relative price of the good in the world market should fall somewhere in between both countries prices


\[\begin{align*} P_{c}^{H} &< P_{c}^{W} < P_{c}^{F} \\ \\ \dfrac{7}{9} &< P_{c}^{W} < \dfrac{12}{10} \end{align*}\]

Let the World Price be \[ P_{c}^{W} = 1 \Rightarrow \text{Slope} = -1 \]

Free Trade

There are gains to be had for both countries to benefit from trade. How do we determine who produces what?

  • The pattern of exports and imports is determined by Opportunity Costs of production in each country.

  • Countries will export the good in which they have the Comparative Advantage and import the other good \(\Rightarrow\) they will specialize and only produce the export good

  • We can think of this in terms prices as well:

    • The price of coffee at Home is 7/9 and at Foreign is 12/10
    • There is a higher return for Home Producers to sell their coffee in Foreign so they will export

Gains From Trade When Specialization Occurs

Home Makes Only Coffee

Foreign Makes Only Tea

Gains From Trade With No Absolute Advantage

What matters most for the purposes of trade is not a country’s absolute advantage but its comparative advantage

  • Differences in absolute advantage do not eliminate gains from trade

Up until now, we have not mentioned wage differences across countries.

  • This is something that is usually talked about in the real world when we hear about concerns of exploitation in foreign countries or offshoring of jobs

Living Standards / Incomes Across Countries

The price of goods we just found were relative prices which means it is a ratio of the value of one good over the other

We assumed \(P_{c}^{W} = 1\) which means that the actual price of goods are equal to each other, not that one unit of coffee is worth $1

Knowing relative prices allows us to find relative wages as well:

  • Economies operate under Perfect Competition which implies zero profits
    • Workers are paid at cost of producing the good
  • Workers earn “units of goods” they produce
  • Since we know relative prices, we can figure out relative wages

Living Standards / Incomes Across Countries

Let the price of a unit of coffee be $3. If the relative world price is 1, then what is the world price of tea?

  • Price of tea is also $3

Each Home worker makes 9 units of coffee per labor unit. Since they get paid what they produce, wages are simply:

\[ \text{wage}_{c}^{H} = \text{productivity} * P_{c}^{W} = 9 * 3 = 27 \]

\[ \text{wage}_{t}^{F} = \text{productivity} * P_{t}^{W} = 12 * 3 = 36 \]

The relative wage of Home workers is \(\dfrac{w^{H}}{w^{F}} = \dfrac{27}{36} = \dfrac{3}{4}\)

Flaws of the Ricardo Model

The Ricardian Model does a great job at providing a basic prediction that countries should tend to export goods in which they have relatively high productivity

  • This has been confirmed by studies over the years

But it is not without some faults:

  • It predicts an extreme degree of specialization that we do not observe in the real world
  • It assumes away effects of trade on the distribution of incomes within countries which ignores the fact that not all benefit from trade equally
  • Misses differences in resources among countries
    • Our next model addresses this

Next Topic

  • Heckscher-Ohlin Trade Model

Reading

Assignment(s) DUE BEFORE CLASS!